Rethinking Kirschner v. J.P. Morgan: How Securities and Banking Laws Should Apply to Syndicated Loans

Introduction

Shortly after the financial crash that spiraled into the Great Depression, Congress passed extensive laws governing securities and securities markets.[1] These securities laws protect investors by imposing disclosure requirements and liability upon issuers for fraudulent practices.[2] Absent an exception, the laws require disclosing material information or an exemption from the disclosure process[3] and provide a private right of action for material misstatements and omissions.[4] These protections are more extensive than common law fraud claims.[5] More importantly, these protections are integral to the efficiency and stability of capital markets.[6] Congress’s intent in passing these laws was to protect investors from bad actors and to substitute a policy of full disclosure for a policy of caveat emptor, or “buyer beware,” in securities markets.[7]

Since Congress passed the Securities Acts in the 1930s, financial markets have become infinitely more complex. They have also become significantly opaquer, as issuers have found ways to gain exposure to capital markets without the disclosure—and the accompanying liability—required by securities laws. Certain markets for such assets, such as the $656 billion collateralized loan obligation (CLO) market and the nearly $1.2 trillion leveraged loan market, intentionally exist outside the scope of securities laws, likely contrary to Congress’s intent.[8]

In May 2020, the District Court for the Southern District of New York in Kirschner v. JPMorgan Chase Bank[9] gave a judicial stamp of approval to these opaque debt markets; the court determined a $1.775 billion syndicated loan distributed to hundreds of investors was not a security. The court analogized the loans at issue in Kirschner to loans like those delivered in consumer financings, short-term loans secured by a lien on a small business, or mortgages. In its incorrect doctrinal analysis, the Kirschner court ignored the intent of the securities laws in favor of a broad, judicially constructed exemption that excluded syndicated loans from securities laws’ reach. By ruling that a syndicated loan is not a security, the court stripped investors of the protections afforded to them by the securities laws. Considering the goals of the securities laws, this Note argues that Congress should classify syndicated loans as securities.

However, if syndicated loans are securities—as this Note suggests they should be—Congress should exclude these loans from the Volcker Rule, which would otherwise prohibit banks from holding securities. Calling syndicated loans securities alone could be catastrophic to the U.S. economy because it would implicate trading and ownership restrictions under the Volcker Rule. Passed in the wake of the 2008 Great Financial Crisis, the Dodd-Frank Act, enabling the Volcker Rule, which, among other things, limits what assets a bank may hold.[10] Banks are limited in owning and trading funds that own securities by the “covered funds” provision of the Volcker Rule.[11] Under the Volcker Rule’s covered funds provision,[12] banks may not hold a loan securitization—such as a CLO—with more than 5 percent securities.[13] If a syndicated loan is a security, then CLOs would consist of significantly more than 5 percent securities, meaning that banks would need to sell their nearly $100 billion in CLO holdings immediately. This massive liquidation would cause financial distress and disrupt lending markets for capital-starved companies.

To adhere to the intent of the securities laws and preserve financial stability, this Note recommends Congress clarify the status of syndicated loans as securities and exclude them from coverage under the Volcker Rule. This new law would promote the disclosure of material information about syndicated loans and provide recourse for those whom securities issuers defraud. Additionally, this proposed law would protect bank stability and adhere to existing statutory mandates regarding bank holdings.

This Note proceeds as follows: Part I provides readers with background information about syndicated lending, leveraged loans, and CLOs. Part II explains the effect of the securities laws on market participants; how securities laws apply to syndicated loans, leveraged loans, and CLOs; and why the laws should apply to syndicated loans. Part III considers the effects of classifying syndicated loans as securities under relevant banking laws. Part IV concludes the Note by arguing that legislative action is necessary to close a judicially created loophole that currently allows syndicated loans to avoid classification as securities.

PDF: Joel Crank,* Rethinking Kirschner v. J.P. Morgan: How Securities and Banking Laws Should Apply to Syndicated Loans

I. The Leveraged Loan Market

This Part provides the necessary background on how the syndicated loan, leveraged loan, and CLO markets operate and commingle. “A syndicated loan . . . is financing offered by a group of lenders—referred to as a syndicate—who work together to provide funds for a single borrower.”[14] Syndicated loan deals are enormous, often for hundreds of millions or even billions of dollars.[15] Syndicated loan deals require more than one lender to bear the risk of default because of the size of the deal.[16] Borrowers have used syndicated loans to finance some of the largest and most capital-intensive projects created, such as building the Panama Canal.[17] However, a relatively new and increasingly prevalent financial instrument is the “leveraged loan.”[18]

Leveraged loans are syndicated loans to large, distressed borrowers, often with poor protections for creditors.[19] The term “leveraged” refers to the high levels of debt the borrowing company holds.[20] Leveraged loans have become far more prevalent and controversial in financial markets as potentially unstable investments. The leveraged loan market expanded dramatically after the Great Financial Crisis in 2008, growing from $497 billion in 2010 to around $1.2 trillion in 2019.[21] As discussed in Part II, the Kirschner decision allowed the leveraged loan market to remain largely outside the scope of federal securities law, and this unregulated status makes the market notoriously opaque.[22] Commentators draw parallels between the degradation in subprime and Alt-A mortgage lending standards preceding the Great Financial Crisis in 2008 and the increasing prevalence of “cov-lite” leveraged loans.[23] “Cov-lite” stands for “covenant-lite,” describing a loan with fewer restrictions on the borrower and fewer protections for the lender. The percentage of cov-lite leveraged loans outstanding has risen from below 10 percent in 2010 to approximately 77 percent of leveraged loans outstanding in 2018.[24] As the market has grown and covenant protections have diminished, the leveraged loan market has received increasing attention from financial regulators,[25] commentators,[26] and members of Congress.[27]

Although financial analysts and commentators have not adopted a universal definition of a “leveraged loan,”[28] this Note adopts the most common metric for defining and quantifying leveraged loans⎯a metric used by S&P Global and the Loan Syndications and Trading Association (LSTA). This definition includes any syndicated loan that is (1) rated BB+ or lower;[29] or (2) is not rated or rated BBB- or higher but has (a) a spread of LIBOR +125 or higher,[30] and (b) is secured by a first or second lien.[31] Debt that rated less than BBB- is considered “non-investment grade,” so leveraged loans by definition include all non-investment-grade loans.[32] The definition also includes all investments for which investors demand 1.25 percent interest above a popular benchmark rate.[33] Because many government reports rely on data gathered by S&P Global and the LSTA, this definition most accurately encapsulates the data used throughout this Note.

Collateralized loan obligations (CLOs) are structured financial products that pool multiple loans—often syndicated loans—into a diversified portfolio, then cut the portfolio into sections called “tranches.”[34] The CLO then sells interests in each tranche to investors based on the investor’s risk preference.[35] As borrowers make payments on the underlying loans, the cash flow is aggregated then trickles down the stack of tranches, paying off all of the debt in the highest-rated AAA tranche first, ensuring this tranche is effectively risk-free.[36] After the payments pay off all debts in the AAA tranche, the cash flow continues to subordinate tranches in the same manner.[37] The lowest tranche, the equity tranche, retains any excess cash flow beyond what is obligated to the senior tranches, but it also absorbs the first losses from defaulting borrowers.[38] Investors earn a higher return by investing in lower tranches to compensate for the risk of the investment.[39] Investment in a loan portfolio, such as a CLO, reduces any one firm’s exposure to a single borrower and spreads the danger of a borrower’s default across multiple lenders in a process known as “diversification.”[40]

Leveraged loans remain outside of the scope of the Securities Acts, likely by design. Banks provide a substantial amount of capital to CLOs, which in turn fund leveraged loan markets by buying the highest rated (AAA-rated) tranches of debt. However, the Volcker Rule prohibits banks from acquiring or retaining “ownership interests” in “covered funds” for investment purposes.[41] Regulators have interpreted the Volcker Rule as prohibiting banks from acquiring or retaining ownership interests in CLOs that hold securities, as defined in the Securities Acts, subject to minor limitations.[42] If syndicated loans were securities, the Volcker Rule would force banks to sell many of their CLO holdings.

II. Syndicated Loan Participations Should Be Securities

In the wake of the Wall Street Crash of 1929, Congress enacted a massive federal regulatory regime for securities, including the Securities Act of 1933 (“Securities Act”) and Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (“Exchange Act”) (collectively, the “Securities Acts”).[43] The purpose of the Securities Acts, at least in part, is to provide investors with financial and other significant information concerning securities offered for public sale.[44] The Securities Acts also created incentives for issuers to avoid the various costs of offering “securities” to the public market.[45] Congress added legislation, most recently the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and the Consumer Protection Act of 2010, to the Securities Acts to increase market transparency and stability.[46] This Part first discusses the implications of an asset being a security, then discusses securities law theory and jurisprudence to explain why the District Court for the Southern District of New York wrongly decided Kirschner. Finally, the Part concludes with a discussion of the jurisprudence and public policy considerations that should influence legislative reclassification of syndicated loans.

A. Implications of Regulation Under the Securities Laws

Though the application of the Securities Acts protects investors, issuers often seek to avoid classification as a security because such classification is expensive, creates liability, and restricts the individuals who may hold such securities. If an issuer of a note, such as a syndicated loan, fails to rebut the presumption that the note is a security under the Reves test,[47] the issuer will face an expensive set of compliance hurdles and will be liable for any material misstatements or omissions it makes. For example, the security must undergo registration and disclosure or be exempt from the process, and the persons trading these securities must register with federal and state compliance enforcing agencies.[48] Moreover, people or entities selling securities may be administratively or judicially liable for their actions, and parties involved in the securities industry are subject to antifraud liability enforced by private plaintiffs or the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC).[49] This Section will explain issuers’ registration and disclosure requirements and provide a high-level overview of Rule 10b-5⎯one of the most powerful tools for private parties to defend against securities fraud.

1. Registration and Disclosure

One of the main ways Congress sought to prevent fraud was through a registration and disclosure process requisite to selling securities to the public. An issuer of securities must either file a registration statement with the SEC before it sells those securities to the investing public,[50] or only sell exempt securities.[51] Registration is an expensive and time-consuming process that increases the cost of raising capital and intrudes into a company’s inner workings.[52] Moreover, registration creates liability for many parties.[53] If the security is registered, many stakeholders are liable for material misstatements and omissions⎯the issuer, people who signed the registration statement, directors, experts, and underwriters, to name a few.[54] Alternatively, an issuer can sell exempt securities.[55] While exempt securities can decrease the cost of registration, the exemption will not entirely avoid the associated attorneys’ fees and other related expenses of issuing a security.[56] Nor does exemption eliminate the applicability and accompanying penalties of securities laws’ antifraud provisions.[57]

Even securities professionals who conduct business in securities markets are subject to substantial regulation.[58] Broker-dealers,[59] investment advisors,[60] mutual funds,[61] private funds,[62] and credit rating agencies[63] are all regulated by government bodies. Any party that violates the rules of the Securities Acts or any other law regulating securities markets and their participants can be both civilly and criminally liable.[64] For instance, if a seller fails to comply with securities registration rules, the buyer may sue to recover the price they paid for the security minus any money they recovered by selling it (recission damages).[65] Likewise, if a registration statement contains a materially false or misleading statement, the buyer may sue to recover damages.[66] The broad language of the Securities Acts also creates liability for negligent misrepresentations,[67] and the government may prosecute willful violations of the Securities Acts by up to five years imprisonment and fines of up to $10,000.[68] In creating such an extensive regulatory scheme for securities, Congress ensured accurate information is available to investors.

2. Rule 10b-5 Antifraud Protections

As the Supreme Court noted in Lorenzo v. SEC, the “basic purpose” of the securities laws is “to substitute a philosophy of full disclosure for the philosophy of caveat emptor . . . .”[69] Congress delegated broad authority to the SEC to enforce the provisions of the Securities Acts under section 17 of the Securities Act,[70] which prohibits the sale of securities that (1) employ a “device, scheme, or artifice to defraud,” (2) “obtain money or property by means of any untrue statement . . . ,” or (3) engage in “any transaction . . . which . . . would operate as a fraud.”[71] The SEC later created a private cause of action with the Exchange Act’s antifraud rule⎯Rule 10b-5. Utilizing the language of section 17 of the Securities Act and deriving authority from section 10(b) of the Exchange Act, Rule 10b-5 states as follows:

It shall be unlawful for any person, directly or indirectly, by the use of any means or instrumentality of interstate commerce, or of the mails or of any facility of any national securities exchange,

(a) To employ any device, scheme, or artifice to defraud,

(b) To make any untrue statement of a material fact or to omit to state a material fact necessary in order to make the statements made, in the light of the circumstances under which they were made, not misleading, or

(c) To engage in any act, practice, or course of business which operates or would operate as a fraud or deceit upon any person,

in connection with the purchase or sale of any security.[72]

Rule 10b-5 intends to ensure full disclosure by creating a private cause of action that permits actual purchasers and sellers to sue issuers for material misstatements or omissions in securities disclosures.[73] For example, investors have sued under Rule 10b-5 in cases where issuers failed to adequately disclose possible adverse effects from a drug,[74] particularly poor investments by a company,[75] or even pending lawsuits against the issuer.[76] The expansive nature of Rule 10b‑5 makes it a valuable tool for plaintiffs that parties involved in securities transactions have defrauded.

Rule 10b-5’s material misstatement or omission rule encourages issuers to communicate with investors clearly and accurately, and its protections extend beyond the protections of common law fraud.[77] This cause of action applies to all issuances of securities, even if they are exempt from registration under the Securities Acts.[78] Under Rule 10b‑5, a plaintiff must show that the defendant (1) made misstatements or omissions of material fact (2) with scienter (3) in connection with the purchase or sale of securities (4) upon which the plaintiffs relied and (5) that the plaintiffs’ reliance was the proximate cause of their injury.[79] To prove reliance, a lawsuit alleging a Rule 10b-5 violation may use the “fraud on the market theory” where the plaintiff need only show (1) an alleged misrepresentation or omission was publicly known, (2) the alleged misrepresentation or omission was material, (3) either (A) the investors relied upon the misstatement or omission, or (B) the security traded in an efficient market,[80] and (4) the plaintiff (or class of plaintiffs, as is often the case) traded the stock between the time the defendant made the misrepresentation and when the truth was revealed.[81] Proving reliance in such a manner expands Rule 10b‑5 liability well past the reaches of common law fraud actions.[82] A class of plaintiffs need only show a securities market is efficient to earn class certification under Rule 10b-5. In contrast, a class in a common law fraud case must show reliance on the misstatement or omission by each member of the class. Because of the cost of bringing a securities fraud claim, plaintiffs seeking recovery almost always require class certification to make the action viable.

Another reason Rule 10b-5 is more protective of investors than common law fraud is the breadth of the legal framework. Generally, a party’s silence does not amount to fraud under common law.[83] Though there are numerous exceptions to this common law rule, Rule 10b‑5 covers significantly more ground. The Rule creates a duty to disclose material information to investors: it covers transactions where parties are induced to buy or sell “without disclosing to them material facts that reasonably could have been expected to influence their decisions.”[84] Though “Rule 10b-5(b) [does] not create an affirmative duty to disclose any and all material information,”[85] it appears to be broader than common law fraud claims.[86] In addition, violations of section 10(b) and Rule 10b-5 are federal questions and, accordingly, may be brought in federal court.[87] Rule 10b-5 allows claims across the country to be aggregated in a single venue and adjudicated, increasing the size of the plaintiff class and decreasing the cost of the action.

To exemplify the importance of Rule 10b-5, consider the Kirschner case.[88] If the Kirschner court correctly decided that the loans at issue were securities, the hundreds of funds composed of individuals’ retirement money most likely would be entitled to relief from being defrauded.[89] If the Kirschner syndicated loan were a security, Rule 10b-5 would likely have applied, and the parties probably would have settled.[90] Taking the plaintiffs’ allegations as true,[91] the issuers and arranging banks violated Rule 10b‑5 by creating documents that misrepresented that the borrower was exposed to no material litigation and that the borrower complied with all applicable regulations and laws. These misstatements were material because the borrower had been exposed to material litigation, had not complied with applicable regulations and laws, and was forced into bankruptcy because of the undisclosed litigation and legal noncompliance.[92] Since the offering documents contained misstatements about the borrower, the plaintiffs could show evidence of conscious misbehavior or recklessness; they could show scienter. Finally, because the misstatements were on offering documents, had the loan been a security, the misstatements would have been in connection with the purchase and sale of a security. The plaintiffs relied upon the offering documents, and that reliance was the cause of their injury. Thus, the plaintiffs could meet the requirements of Rule 10b-5. However, because the court did not consider the loans securities, the plaintiffs had to rely upon common law fraud claims. The court has since denied the plaintiff’s motion for leave to amend the complaint to expand the plaintiff’s fraud theories because such amendments would be futile.[93]

B. Securities Laws Should Cover Syndicated Loans

A necessary condition for regulation under the securities laws is that the asset is a “security.”[94] To determine whether an asset is a security, a court first looks at what type of asset exists and then applies the appropriate judicially constructed test.[95] The court looks to the substance of the transaction, not its form.[96] The following Section discusses some of the economic theory underlying securities regulation, reviews some hallmark cases in securities law, and examines the Kirschner decision to explain why the court decided the case incorrectly.

1. The Theory Underlying Securities Laws

Protecting investors, disclosing information, and inspiring trust in capital markets were at the core of Congress’s reasons for passing the Securities Acts.[97] Where markets lack information, they may break down, bubbles[98] may form, and the bubbles bursting may create systemic stress. The economic theory supporting the law is the Efficient Capital Market Hypothesis, the idea that capital markets reflect an asset’s value when material information is available to the public.[99] Markets that lack the disclosure required under the Securities Acts are prone to more risk,[100] and opaque markets preceded many financial crises.[101] Thus, the requirement that securities be registered and issuers disclose material information to the investing public means securities laws attempt to push the value of securities toward their intrinsic value. Likewise, with antifraud liability, the implied costs of misstatements or nondisclosure encourage securities issuers to provide as much relevant information to the investing public as possible, so the aggregate knowledge of the market may accurately appraise the value of the security.[102]

Opaque markets preceded many of the most severe American economic crises. In October 1929, the U.S. stock market crashed, leading to the Great Depression.[103] In the bubble that preceded the stock market crash in 1929, investors became more speculative and overconfident, but access to market information was limited.[104] In response to the market failure preceding the Great Depression, Congress passed the Securities Acts to prevent abuses by company insiders and market professionals by requiring more disclosure and by subjecting bad actors to liability for misinformation provided to the public.[105]

More recently, institutional investors failed to recognize the presence of risky debt in opaque mortgage-backed securities, leading to the 2008 Great Financial Crisis.[106] On one side of the transaction, the mortgage securitization industry was fraudulently approving people for home loans, in many extreme cases giving “NINJA” and jumbo loans to individuals who could not afford them.[107] On the other side of the transactions, market participants securitized these already-fraudulent loans into ever-more complex assets.[108] Like syndicated loans into CLOs, these risky mortgages were packaged as collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) and even re-securitizations of the risky CDO tranches into CDO-squared and -cubed.[109] Financial institutions also provided insurance on these hyper-complex assets called “credit default swaps,” which became the catalyst between risky mortgages and the worldwide Great Financial Crisis.[110] Ultimately, institutional investors’ inability to access information led to the loss of over 12.5 million jobs, $11 trillion in stock market capitalization, $3.4 trillion in retirement account losses, and $7 trillion in real estate losses.[111] The intent of securities laws—such as the Securities Acts and the Dodd-Frank Act—is to prevent financial crises like the Great Financial Crisis by limiting opaque markets and bolstering efficient markets.[112]

2. Reves and Howey—How Courts Analyze Securities

The intent of Congress in passing the Securities Acts, and courts’ interpretations of the acts, will drive the analysis about whether a syndicated loan is a security. To understand the Supreme Court’s initial interpretation of the term “security,” one must look to SEC v. W. J. Howey Co. where the Court first devised a test for determining what constitutes an “investment contract.”[113] To be covered by the Securities Act, an instrument must be one of those defined in section 2(a) – such as “stock,” a “note,” or an “investment contract.”[114] In Howey, the Court defined an investment contract as (1) an investment of money (2) in a common enterprise (3) premised on the reasonable expectation of profit (4) derived solely[115] from the efforts of others.[116] Implicit in the Howey test is the Court’s desire to protect passive investors who have little or no control and face collective action obstacles. Relying heavily on the intent of Congress, the Court impliedly intended to protect capital flow and investors’ money from fraud and other malfeasance, thereby increasing trust and investment in capital markets.[117] Though the Howey test does not directly apply to notes, the Howey Court’s analysis supports Congress’s goals of market access to information and protection from fraud, which are implicit in the Securities Acts.

Where the financial investment in question is a note,[118] courts will apply the Reves test.[119] When Congress defined “securities” in the Securities Acts, it did not want the laws to apply to every transaction where parties exchanged capital for an expected return.[120] Section 2(a) of the Securities Act (where the term “security” is defined) limits the definition of security with the phrase “unless the context otherwise requires . . . ,”[121] indicating Congress’s intent to avoid subjecting every exchange of assets to securities laws.[122] Accordingly, the Reves Court specified that “‘any note’ should not be interpreted to mean literally ‘any note,’ but must be understood against the backdrop of what Congress was attempting to accomplish in enacting the Securities Acts.”[123] To analyze whether a security is a “note,” the Court adopted a “family resemblance” test.[124] Under the family resemblance test, the issuer of a note may “rebut the presumption that a note is a security if it can show the note in question ‘bear[s] a strong family resemblance’ to an item on the judicially crafted list of exceptions . . . or convinces the court to add a new instrument to the list.’”[125] This list is as follows:

[1] the note delivered in consumer financing, [2] the note secured by a mortgage on a home, [3] the short-term note secured by a lien on a small business or some of its assets, [4] the note evidencing a ‘character’ loan to a bank customer, [5] short-term notes secured by an assignment of accounts receivable, [6] a note which simply formalizes an open-account debt incurred in the ordinary course of business (particularly if, as in the case of the customer of a broker, it is collateralized)[126] [, and 7] notes evidencing loans by commercial banks for current operations.[127]

The Reves Court also crafted a four-factor test to analogize notes to the instruments on this non-exhaustive list and contemplate additions to the list.[128] When analogizing a note to a non-security debt contract, a court looks to (1) the motivation of the buyer and seller, (2) “the plan of distribution,” (3) “the reasonable expectations of the investing public,” and (4) the presence of alternate regulatory regimes or other factors that may protect investors.[129]

The first factor—motivations of the buyer and seller—contemplates whether the issuer of the note uses proceeds for a general business purpose (whereby it would more likely be a security), or if the borrower uses it to buy consumer goods or for some other “commercial” purpose (where it would more likely be a non-security).[130] This factor adopts an objective reasonable person test.[131] Specifically, Reves analysis requires a court to consider how a transaction is “most naturally conceived” by investors.[132]

The second factor, the plan of distribution, instructs courts to “determine whether [the note] is an instrument in which there is ‘common trading for speculation or investment.’”[133] A note need not be traded on an exchange; however, it must be offered and sold to a broad segment of the public for the plan of distribution factor to weigh in favor of a “security.”[134] Where restrictions on the notes “work[] to prevent the loan participations from being sold to the general public,” or “only institutional and corporate entities were solicited” for sale, the distribution plan is seemingly narrow—meaning that the note is less likely to be a security.[135]

The third Reves factor inquires into the “reasonable expectations of the investing public: The Court will consider instruments ‘securities’ based on public expectations, even where an economic analysis of the circumstances of the particular transaction might suggest that the instruments are not ‘securities’ as used in that transaction.”[136] Where purchasers of the debt are sophisticated and given ample notice that the instruments were participations in loans—not investments—the reasonable expectation should be that the instrument is not a security.[137]

The fourth and final factor in the Reves test instructs the court to look for the presence of other regulatory schemes “which significantly [reduce] the risk of the instrument, thereby rendering the Securities Act unnecessary.”[138] Insurance through the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) and applicable banking laws,[139] regulation under the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA),[140] or policy guidelines issued to address the sale of loan participations by the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency,[141] for example, weigh against applying the securities laws to the asset.[142] These other regulatory regimes would, in effect, make the application of the Securities Acts redundant.[143]

The Reves factors are considered holistically, with no one factor dispositive of the outcome.[144] Where one of the factors does not lead to a clear conclusion, but the other factors indicate a note is not a security, the court may still conclude that the note is not a security.[145] Even where one of the factors indicates the note is a security, the court may still find the note is not a security.[146]

3. The Kirschner Decision Deviates from Reves and Howey

In May 2020, the U.S. District Court for the Southern District of New York decided that syndicated term loans are not “securities” as defined by the Securities Acts.[147] Thus, investors in syndicated term loans, or at least those resembling the loans at issue, are not entitled to the protections of the Securities Acts.[148] Consequently, the issuers of the syndicated loans at issue were not required to disclose material information to syndicates of hundreds of institutional investors, nor were they liable for material misstatements or omissions under Rule 10b-5.[149] Instead of increasing the availability of information in capital markets as Congress intended when passing the Securities Acts, the Kirshner decision deprived investors of any transparency.[150]

The plaintiff in Kirschner was a trust consisting of “roughly 400 mutual funds, hedge funds, and other institutional investors (the ‘Investors’).”[151] The defendants were JPMorgan Chase, Citibank, SunTrust Bank, and some of their subsidiaries (“Arrangers”).[152] The Arrangers structured and organized a $1.775 billion syndicated loan transaction funding Millennium Laboratories LLC (“Millennium”)⎯a California-based urine drug testing company.[153] The syndicated loan transaction “proceeded in three inter-related and contemporaneous steps”[154] where JPMorgan Chase performed the initial funding, Millennium sold loan participations to the Investors, and then the Investors became obligated to JPMorgan Chase to purchase the amount of the loan for which they subscribed.[155] The transaction closed in April 2014, triggering the Investors’ obligations.[156]

In November 2015, after two unrelated lawsuits concluded unfavorably for Millennium and “the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services threatened to debar Millennium [from government contracting] based on allegations of illegal billing practices,” Millennium declared bankruptcy.[157] Millennium’s bankruptcy petition led to the formation of the trust in the present case.[158] The Investors’ claims arise out of, among other things, the Arrangers’ alleged negligent misrepresentation and violations of securities laws.[159] According to the Investors, some Arrangers created offering materials that contained misstatements and omissions that induced the Investors’ purchase of the Millennium notes, Chase did not give contemporaneous notice of the adverse legal actions or Medicare’s threat to debar Millennium, and the Arrangers failed to perform adequate due diligence on Millennium before selling the loans, among other violations of contract laws.[160]

Applying the Reves family resemblance test, the Kirschner court determined the loans at issue were not “securities” as defined by the Securities Acts because the syndicated loans were “analogous to the enumerated category of loans issued by banks for commercial purposes.”[161] The court reasoned that the first Reves factor was neutral, but the remaining factors weighed against finding that the syndicated loan was a “security.”[162] When analyzing the motivations of the buyer and seller—the first Reves factor—the Kirschner court determined that the motivations of the two parties did not “weigh heavily in either direction.”[163] Millennium’s purpose in the transaction was “commercial”: it used the debt to finance loan repayment and pay a dividend.[164] However, the Investors acquired the notes as an investment, and the Investors were predominantly pension and retirement funds that purchased the notes for investment portfolios.[165] The court decided this question correctly, but its proper analysis of the securities laws ended with the first factor.

The Kirschner court misapplied the second Reves factor, which looks to the issuer’s plan of distribution. In the eyes of the court, the plan of distribution weighed against classifying the loan as a security since the issuers solicited investment managers and other institutional investors.[166] The “[solicitation] of hundreds of investment managers across the country”[167] did little to change the court’s conclusion, since the defendants only solicited the notes to institutional and corporate entities, while restrictions on the notes “worked to prevent the loan participations from being sold to the general public.”[168] Nevertheless, this analysis was incorrect. It failed to recognize the economic reality of the transaction. When analogizing to the Reves family—all of which traditionally have only two participants: a lender (typically a bank) and a borrower[169]—the hundreds of investors participating in a loan looks much less like a member of the Reves family. Though covenants in the loan prohibited sales to the general public, hundreds, or even thousands, of people were exposed to the risk of this loan either directly as an investor or indirectly as an investor in a fund that held these notes. The economic reality of this transaction indicates the syndicated loan was a security because the Arrangers broadly offered the notes, unlike the Reves family, which typically consists of a small loan between two parties. The participation of hundreds of investors looks like an investment of money in a “common enterprise” premised on the reasonable expectation of profit derived solely from the efforts of others[170]⎯not a loan delivered in consumer financing, a small business loan, or a mortgage.[171]

To determine the reasonable expectations of the investing public—the third Reves factor—the Kirschner court looked to the agreements between the parties and found that this factor weighed against classifying the notes as securities.[172] According to the court, “the governing documents . . . made clear to the parties that they were participating in a lending transaction, not investing in securities.”[173] Further, the credit agreement made repeated references to the “loan documents” and used words such as “loan” and “lender” instead of the term “investor.”[174] According to the court, “[i]nterests in bank debt . . . typically have been considered not to constitute ‘securities’ for purposes of the securities laws.”[175] The court also found no precedent holding that a syndicated term loan is a security and, therefore, found that the reasonable expectations of the investing public weigh heavily against these notes being securities.[176] Contrary to the court’s findings, however, from a generalized perspective, reasonable observers would probably believe these are the type of asset that the securities laws would regulate.[177] Indeed, there were hundreds of participants to this broadly syndicated loan and, by the court’s admission, the participants viewed these like an investment.[178]

Finally, when the Kirschner court analyzed the fourth Reves factor, it concluded that the existence of federal banking regulations also weighed in favor of non-security treatment for the loans.[179] The Kirschner court found sufficient “existence of another regulatory scheme” in federal banking regulations because multiple federal banking regulators set policy guidelines,[180] unlike the “uncollateralized and uninsured” instruments with “no risk-reducing factor” at issue in Reves.[181] However, it is worth noting that banking regulations alone should not have a determinative effect. Looking to banking regulations as an indicator for whether an asset is a security leads to a circularity problem. Because banks cannot trade securities or have an ownership interest in funds that hold securities,[182] the court’s consideration of banking laws counterintuitively means that securities look less like securities under the fourth Reves factor and non-securities look more like securities. Stated differently, a bank can own a syndicated loan because it is not a security, and the syndicated loan is not a security because the bank can own it. Even if banking regulations limit the risk a bank may assume, such regulations differ significantly from the comprehensive legislative and regulatory scheme like ERISA.[183]

Moving away from the Kirschner court’s analysis, one can further distinguish the Reves family from syndicated loans by looking at the examples in Reves.[184] All of the notes in the Reves family⎯those that are not considered “securities” for the application of the Securities Acts—are relatively small loans made to individuals or small businesses.[185] One can easily distinguish these small loans from the $1.775 billion syndicated loans funded by hundreds of investors at issue in Kirschner.[186] Indeed, the only type of note listed in Reves that is comparable to the Kirschner syndicated loan is a note “evidencing loans by commercial banks for current operations.”[187] However, the syndicated loan in Kirschner is so drastically different than a note in consumer financing, home mortgages, short-term small business loans, character loans, notes secured by accounts receivable, and notes that formalize open-account debts incurred in the ordinary course of business that it is hard to imagine the Reves Court would include it in the family. Because a syndicated loan is nothing like the members of the Reves family, it stands to reason that it would not deserve an exemption from the Securities Acts because it does not bear a resemblance to those non-securities.[188]

Lastly, the Howey test indicates that the Kirschner syndicated loans are securities.[189] Under Howey, this loan would be an investment contract because this syndicated loan is (1) an investment of money (2) in a common enterprise (3) premised on the reasonable expectation of profit (4) derived from the efforts of Millennium.[190] Unlike in Kirschner, the Howey Court recognized Congress’s intent to protect passive investors who have little control over the company and to shield investors from fraud and malfeasance.[191] Because the lenders in a syndicate have no control over the single loan agreement contract that the arrangers negotiate, the passive role of the syndicate participants resembles investors in securities.[192] Congress’s goal was to protect these passive investors[193]—a goal which should apply to notes, even if the Howey test does not.

C. According to Public Policy and Reves, Syndicated Loans Should Be Securities

Trading broadly syndicated term loans through a two-step process allows the risky $1.2 trillion leveraged-loan market[194] to exist almost entirely outside of regulatory scrutiny, meaning borrowers can still access capital from public market investors without disclosing large amounts of material information. Currently, to avoid the regulatory scrutiny of the securities laws, a borrower seeking money may go to a bank to obtain a large amount of capital. If the borrower’s capital requirements are high enough, the bank may arrange a syndicated loan deal by finding investors, structuring the deal, and providing the capital to the borrower. Sellers resell interests in these loans to institutional investors through either direct loan holdings[195] or interests in collateralized loan obligations.[196] Because institutional investors are simply investment vehicles for the broad public,[197] companies may still access a massive capital market while circumventing the need to comply with the expensive and revealing security registration and disclosure requirements.

By reclassifying syndicated term loans as “securities” as defined in section 2(a)(1) of the Securities Act,[198] issuers will be required to disclose material information to investors, and they will be liable for any misstatements or omissions made to investors. Disclosure requirements of the securities laws will increase the availability and accuracy of information about corporate borrowers. Though borrowers may utilize private placement exemptions to avoid the complex process of issuing a public security, they must still disclose some information.[199] These private placements of loan syndications will exempt the offerings from registration, but they will still be subject to the antifraud liability rules found in section 10(b)[200] and Rule 10b-5.[201] Because antifraud rules apply, issuers will be more careful about the information it discloses to the syndicate, and issuers, not the investing public, will bear the cost of misstatements and omissions. Correctly applying securities laws to broadly syndicated loans promotes financial stability by increasing publicly available information.

Setting aside Reves, some industry professionals argue that public policy requires syndicated loans be classified as non-securities⎯an argument that deserves great deference. Even when classified as non-securities, disclosure in syndicated loan offerings is still necessary because lenders do not blindly lend hundreds of millions of dollars without understanding who is borrowing their money. Indeed, many proponents of the status quo argue that participants in a syndicate rely on confidential⎯often material non-public information under the securities laws⎯in deciding whether to lend to the borrower.[202] According to the LSTA, “syndicated term loans are originated, syndicated, and traded on the basis of confidential information.”[203] Some argue that should a loan in a syndicate be a security, issuers would have to disclose this information to the market⎯counter to the traditions of loan syndications⎯supplying competitors with key information about the borrowing company. Participants in loan syndicates also point to the bargaining power of a lender in a syndicate compared to an investor in a bond issuance.[204] A lender in a loan syndicate has a direct contractual lending relationship with the borrower so that parties may adjust the terms and conditions of the agreement more readily than the terms of a bond indenture.[205]

Opponents of classifying syndicated loans as securities also point to the expectations of the market. Loans have not traditionally been securities, so the market has grown to expect minimal disclosure requirements and minimal antifraud liability for issuers.[206] Accordingly, syndicated loan market participants “are expected to have the capacity to independently evaluate their transactions in the loan market, to make informed decisions regarding the amount of due diligence that is appropriate under the circumstances, and to undertake such due diligence deemed appropriate by them.”[207] In practice, this places the impetus on lenders to search for information and the cost of any borrower’s concealment on the general public.

Admittedly, many of these arguments are salient, but they fail to consider the possibilities for private placements under section 4(a)(2) of the Securities Act.[208] Issuers may sell securities outside of public markets in a private placement, and counterparties can still be subject to nondisclosure agreements, hiding confidential information from the market.[209] Private placements also do not change lenders’ bargaining status since the same number of lenders may be solicited and these lenders will likely be the same parties. In fact, should the Volcker Rule be amended as described below in Part III, the parties would be in the same position during a private placement loan syndication apart from the application of antifraud liability to issuers. If syndicated loans were securities, Rule 10b-5 would apply, allocating the cost of finding information from the lenders to the borrowers.

Rule 10b-5 is especially significant because of the prevalence of cov-lite lending. Cov-lite refers to the reduction of provisions known as covenants that protect lenders in debt contracts by limiting what a borrower may do⎯such as taking on excessive debt.[210] A covenant is “a part of . . . [a] loan agreement that limits certain actions a . . . [borrower] may take during the term of the loan to protect the lender’s interests.”[211] Covenants will often require borrowers maintain certain financial conditions, refrain from making excessively risky decisions, give lenders additional control over the company’s decisions, or provide information to lenders.[212] In many cases, the absence of covenants will allow flexibility in calculating financial ratios, increasing the likelihood of dishonesty.[213] Given the reduction in protective covenants in leveraged loans,[214] Rule 10b-5 could play an integral role in protecting investors from misstatements by borrowers who have taken too many liberties in calculating their financial numbers. Some argue that cov-lite loans provide necessary mobility to companies, allowing borrowers to adapt in a dynamic business world.[215] While this may be true, Rule 10b-5 could serve as a countervailing force in ensuring that businesses can access capital while still protecting investors from bad actors and borrower malfeasance.

Congress should regulate syndicated loans as securities to increase the availability of material information and allocate the cost of misstatements and omissions to issuers. Given the precedent in Kirschner and prior cases like Banco Espanol,[216] and considering the financial stability implications of reclassifying syndicated loans as discussed in Part III, courts may be hesitant to revise their jurisprudence to classify syndicated loans as securities under Reves. Congress’s intervention is necessary because, as will be discussed in Part III, reclassification implicates banking laws that administrative agencies may not be able to change. Congress must address multiple interconnected areas of law at once to avoid causing massive distress in lending markets.[217]

Finally, if Congress reclassifies syndicated loans as securities, the newly applicable registration requirements, trading limitations, liability rules, and antifraud provisions may slow the speed at which syndicated term loan issuances occur and decrease the frequency at which new loan transactions occur. To obviate these new costs, enforcement agencies may consider creating a new, alternate version of the registration and disclosure requirements to help ameliorate some of the regulatory burdens on loan markets.[218]

III. If Syndicated Loans Are Securities, Congress Must Amend the Volcker Rule to Comply with the Bank Holding Company Act

Calling syndicated loans securities alone could be catastrophic to the U.S. economy because it would implicate trading and ownership restrictions under the Volcker Rule. Passed in the wake of the 2008 Great Financial Crisis, the Dodd-Frank Act enabled bank regulators to create the Volcker Rule, which, among other things, limits what assets a bank may hold.[219] Banks may be limited in owning and trading funds that own securities by the “covered funds” provision of the Volcker Rule.[220] Practically, the covered funds provision means that if syndicated loans are securities, banks may not hold CLOs. Accordingly, if syndicated loans (including all leveraged loans) are securities, banks would have to offload massive amounts of debt previously considered risk-free.[221] To unload billions of dollars of debt quickly would require financial institutions to sell at fire-sale prices,[222] creating massive losses in what banks and bank regulators consider safe investments. Such reclassification would also restrict capital flow from banks to borrowers since banks could no longer trade their loan exposures. Banks and other interest groups have litigated to avoid these adverse consequences and to prevent classifying syndicated loans as securities.[223] This Part first defines the Volcker Rule’s covered funds provision, then reviews the policy considerations for banks should syndicated loans be securities.

A. Defining the Covered Funds Provision

The Volcker Rule, one of the flagship components of the Dodd-Frank Act,[224] amended the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 to prohibit banks from, among other things, “acquir[ing] or retain[ing] any equity, partnership, or other ownership interest in or sponsor[ing] a hedge fund or a private equity fund.”[225] Known as the “covered funds” provision, the Volcker Rule expressly prohibits any banking entity from “directly or indirectly[] acquir[ing] or retain[ing] any ownership interest in or sponsor[ing] a covered fund.”[226] Covered funds traditionally include asset-backed securities, but regulations exempt asset-backed securities composed of loans and other debt securities provided that, among other things, “the aggregate value of such debt securities does not exceed five percent of the aggregate value of loans held [within the asset-backed security].”[227] Under the covered funds provision, where an asset-backed security (such as a CLO) consists of 95 percent or more loans within the collateral pool, a bank may hold the asset.[228]

The Bank Holding Company Act expressly authorized loan securitizations. Section 13(g)(2) of the Act states: “Nothing in this section shall be construed to limit or restrict the ability of a banking entity . . . to sell or securitize loans in a manner otherwise permitted by law.”[229] In the adopting release of the covered funds provision, the Office of the Comptroller of Currency (OCC), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (Fed), Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), and SEC explained the reason for the exemption: the importance of enabling banks to “continue to provide financing to loan borrowers at competitive prices.”[230] According to the agencies, “[l]oan securitizations provide an important avenue for banking entities to obtain investor financing for existing loans, which allows such banks greater capacity to continuously provide financing and lending to their customers.”[231] As such, the Volcker Rule’s covered funds provision permits banks to own, sell, and invest in CLOs. The 2013 version of the covered funds provision allowed banks to hold loan securitizations so long as loan securitizations held only loans and a small number of other assets that were not “securities.”[232]

In 2020, the OCC, Fed, FDIC, and SEC amended the covered funds provision to allow banks holding loan securitizations with up to 5 percent debt securities.[233] However, industry participants criticized the rule, claiming that it impermissibly restricted a bank’s right to hold, sell, and securitize loans under the Bank Holding Company Act.[234] Because the covered funds provision was so restrictive, the agencies amended the rule to permit banks to own securitizations “hold[ing] limited amounts of non-loan assets” to “promote the ability of banking entities to sell or securitize loans” and “respond to investor demand.”[235] The new rule allows banks to hold securitizations with up to 5 percent debt securities[236] to better facilitate Congress’s intent in exempting loan securitizations from the covered funds provision.

B. If Syndicated Loans are Securities, Capital Markets Will Fundamentally Change

If Congress or the courts reclassify syndicated loans as securities, the Volcker Rule will prohibit banks from holding CLOs. If the Volcker Rule were to prohibit bank ownership of CLOs, it would either run afoul of the Bank Holding Company Act, cause massive economic turmoil, or both. Section 13(g)(2) of the Bank Holding Company Act permits banks to sell and securitize loans.[237] The Volcker Rule, which is a regulation, would directly conflict with the statutory requirements of the Bank Holding Company Act, meaning the Volcker Rule would likely be repealed in relevant part.[238] Were this the case, bank regulators would lose their ability to prohibit banks from holding loan collateralizations, and banks may even begin to hold the risky collateralizations the Volcker Rule intended to prevent.

If the Volcker Rule and section 13(g)(2) could both exist, the Rule would prohibit banks from holding CLOs. Accordingly, banks would have to immediately “divest themselves of approximately $86 billion in interests in CLOs holding syndicated term loans—25% of CLOs’ AAA notes.”[239] This divestiture of a significant portion of banks’ assets would cause at least two significant economic events. First, banks would have to sell at fire-sale prices,[240] meaning that banking institutions would sustain heavy losses on their investments.[241] This massive liquidation would impose a tremendous financial burden and force massive losses on what banks previously believed were “risk-free” assets.[242] Placing such a strain on banks, especially during severe economic distress,[243] could be catastrophic and cause disastrous effects on the world economy.[244] To address the fire-sale issues that would occur, legislators could add a grandfather provision allowing banks to hold any CLO they held prior to the date upon which the loans became securities. A grandfather provision, however, is a partial solution to the problem.

The second, and more significant, problem is that a major disruption to the CLO market would likely reduce capital flow to firms.[245] As of the first quarter of 2020, banks held just under $99 billion in CLOs, up about 12 percent from 2019.[246] Banks hold about 16 percent of CLOs outstanding.[247] In October 2020, CLOs held about half of the $1.2 trillion in leveraged loans outstanding.[248] Without the involvement of banks in the market, a significant portion of the capital supplied to the leveraged loan market⎯which ultimately provides much-needed capital to distressed businesses⎯would dry up. Likely, tens of billions of dollars in financing would become unavailable to distressed borrowers, all but sealing borrowers’ and their creditors’ fate in bankruptcy court. Other leveraged loan market participants may invest in the place of banks, but replacing nearly $100 billion with insurance companies, hedge and mutual funds, and other industry participants is unlikely, especially considering banks’ growing role in the CLO market.

Additionally, banks frequently purchase the highest-rated tranches of CLOs, supplying capital to syndicated term loans and loan originators.[249] Other investors may prefer riskier investments with a greater return, meaning they may not step into the banks’ shoes. Alternatively, they may demand a higher return, increasing the cost of capital for already struggling firms. Without the capital from banks funding billions of dollars in the CLO and leveraged loan markets, businesses would have limited access to capital, and global economies would experience a credit crunch.[250]

Given that precedent states syndicated loans are not securities and the adverse consequences of their reclassification, courts ruling that syndicated loans are securities is unlikely. However, if Congress decides to act by classifying syndicated loans as securities as is suggested in Section II.C, then it must simultaneously act to prevent fire-sales and credit crunches in the CLO, syndicated loan, and leveraged loan markets. Congress must accompany any amendment to the securities laws with an amendment to the Bank Holding Company Act. Such action would underscore the importance of section 13(g)(2), which protects banks’ ability to securitize loans.

Some may argue against this proposed Volcker Rule exemption because the Volcker Rule intends to protect banks from taking part in excessively risky investments. This argument overlooks three critical details about bank holdings of CLOs. First, banks already hold CLOs as permitted by the Volcker Rule,[251] so reclassifying the same asset would not lead to increased exposure to the risks associated with CLOs. Second, taken in tandem with the proposed amendments to the Securities Acts, this legislative change decreasing the risk of banks’ investments in CLOs by increasing their access to information about the underlying loan and providing recourse for misrepresentations by the loan’s originators. Finally, as explained above, changing the classification of syndicated loans under the securities laws would likely cause substantial harm to financial stability in the banking system without also amending the Volcker Rule, making an amendment necessary.

Conclusion

This Note discusses the judicial loophole utilized by the syndicated term loan market to avoid securities laws and maintains an opaque lending market. Courts have pushed the boundaries of the Reves test, and in what seems to surpass Congress’s intent, the Kirschner court placed a judicial stamp of approval on the $1.2 trillion opaque leveraged loan market by stating that syndicated loans are not securities. This Note concludes that the Kirschner court erred in its ruling, and the Note suggests a legislative remedy would be appropriate.

Classifying syndicated term loans as securities increases disclosure to investors and shifts the burden of searching for information from investors to issuers. Antifraud liability protects the public’s confidence in capital markets and creates incentives for issuers to avoid material misstatements and omissions. Though financial engineering on the scale that exists today was neither present nor imaginable in the 1930s when Congress passed the Securities Acts, Congress likely intended to regulate opaque, trillion-dollar markets owned by an array of institutional investors. As applied in Kirschner, the Reves test circumvents Congress’s broad-reaching regulatory framework intended to increase publicly available investment information and avoid fraud.

Considering the breadth of the Securities Acts, Congress likely intended to regulate syndicated loans. However, in isolation, classifying a syndicated term loan as a security would cause massive disruption to markets, credit crunches, and fire‑sales, resulting in economic turmoil. To prevent widespread economic distress and honor the Securities Acts’ intent, Congress must amend the definition of a security to include syndicated loans and modify the Bank Holding Company Act to protect the current banking infrastructure and businesses’ access to capital markets.

*Juris Doctor candidate, University of Colorado Law School Class of 2022. I am grateful to Professor Erik Gerding, who inspired my interest in securities law and served as a mentor throughout my time in law school. I also want to thank the numerous members of the University of Colorado Law Review team, without whom writing this Note would not be possible. Most important, special thanks to my mother, Lisa, and my fiancée, Megan, both of whom have endured countless hours of my rambling about securities law and supported me by reading numerous drafts of this Note. All errors are my own.

  1. .Securities Act of 1933, ch. 38, 48 Stat. 74 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 77a); Securities Exchange Act of 1934, ch. 404, 48 Stat. 881 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 78a); Investment Company Act of 1940, ch. 686, 54 Stat. 789 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 80a-1); Investment Advisers Act of 1940, ch. 686, 54 Stat. 847 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 80b-1).
  2. .Infra Section II.B.1.
  3. .15 U.S.C. § 77e(a) (requiring a security’s registration before it can be sold in interstate commerce).
  4. .17 C.F.R. § 240.10b-5 (2021).
  5. .Infra Section II.A.2.
  6. .See infra Section II.B.1 (discussing the efficient market hypothesis); see also What We Do, U.S. Sec. & Exch. Comm’n, https://www.sec.gov/about/what-we-do [https://perma.cc/8PVJ-QPZA] (Nov. 22, 2021) (noting the Securities and Exchange Commission partly exists to maintain “fair, orderly, and efficient markets”).
  7. .SEC v. Cap. Gains Rsch. Bureau, 375 U.S. 180, 186 (1963); see also Lorenzo v. SEC, 139 S. Ct. 1094, 1103 (2019); Black Diamond Fund, LLLP v. Joseph, 211 P.3d 727, 738 (Colo. App. 2009).
  8. .See, e.g., Kirschner ex rel. Millennium Lender Claim Tr. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., No. 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765 (S.D.N.Y. May 22, 2020). For the size of the CLO market, see Kristen Haunss, US CLO Issuance Forecast to Fall in 2020 as Spreads Remain Wide, Reuters (Nov. 27, 2019, 7:15 AM), https://www.reuters.com/article/clo-forecast2020/us-clo-issuance-forecast-to-fall-in-2020-as-spreads-remain-wide-idUSL1N2870GW [https://perma.cc/JN4B-A9RC].
  9. .Kirschner, 2020 WL 2614765, at *1.
  10. .12 U.S.C. § 1851; 17 C.F.R. § 255.10 (2021).
  11. .Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 § 13, 12 U.S.C. § 1841.
  12. .The covered funds provision of the Volcker Rule prohibits “a banking entity . . . [from] acquir[ing] or retain[ing] any ownership interest in or sponsor a covered fund.” 17 C.F.R. § 255.10(a)(1) (2021). A “covered fund,” generally speaking, is an investment fund—like a hedge fund or private equity fund. See id. § 255.10(b).
  13. .A loan securitization holding debt securities is not a “covered fund” so long as the “aggregate value of such debt securities does not exceed five percent of the aggregate value of [the] loans.” 17 C.F.R. § 255.10(c)(8)(i)(E)(1) (2021).
  14. .Troy Segal, Syndicated Loan, Investopedia, https://www.investopedia.com/terms/s/syndicatedloan.asp [https://perma.cc/LUL4-YXDE] (June 22, 2020).
  15. .According to the Corporate Finance Institute, a syndicated loan is always over one million dollars. Syndicated Loan, Corp. Fin. Inst., https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/knowledge/finance/syndicated-loan [https://perma.cc/432G-4ZT6]. But the largest syndicated loan ever (as of 2018) was a $100 billion loan to Broadcom in its $121 billion acquisition of Qualcomm. Alasdair Reilly, Broadcom Gets Record $100 Billion Loan for Qualcomm Buy, Reuters (Feb. 12, 2018), https://www.reuters.com/article/us-broadcom-loan/broadcom-gets-record-100-billion-loan-for-qualcomm-buy-idUSKBN1FW1BU [https://perma.cc/X324-NCC3]. According to the St. Louis Fed, the average loan size of loans made under participation or syndication in the fourth quarter of 2015 was $2,844,000. Fed. Rsrv. Bank of St. Louis, Average Loan Size of Loans Made Under Participation or Syndication, All Commercial Banks, FRED, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/EAFNQ [https://perma.cc/DXP8-NACC] (Jan. 15, 2016).
  16. .“Loan syndication occurs when a single borrower requires a large loan ($1 million or more) that a single lender may be unable to provide, or when the loan is outside the scope of the lender’s risk exposure. Lenders then form a syndicate that allows them to spread the risk and share in the financial opportunity.” Syndicated Loan, supra note 15.
  17. .The Panama Canal was financed by a J.P. Morgan syndicated loan. History of Our Firm, JPMorgan Chase & Co., https://www.jpmorganchase.com/about/our-history [https://perma.cc/4C9U-Z4KM] (choose “1860s-1910s” under “Explore Our History;” then scroll down to “1904 Morgan finances the Panama Canal”).
  18. .See, e.g., Leveraged Loan Primer, S&P Glob.: Mkt. Intel., https://www.spglobal.com/marketintelligence/en/pages/toc-primer/lcd-primer#sec1 [https://perma.cc/6NCD-RSQU].
  19. .Id.
  20. .Will Kenton, Leveraged Loan, Investopedia, https://www.investopedia.com/terms/l/leveragedloan.asp [https://perma.cc/2CJX-LRYE] (Apr. 25, 2021).
  21. .Leveraged Loan Primer, supra note 18.
  22. .See Andrew Osterland, The Booming Loan Market Is Getting Riskier, CNBC (June 25, 2018, 11:58 AM), https://www.cnbc.com/2018/06/21/the-booming-leveraged-loan-market-is-getting-riskier.html [https://perma.cc/JSK3-GGN2] (“This market is a lot more opaque than the bond market. There could be ugly stuff happening under the waterline.”).
  23. .Two salient factors characterize the Great Financial Crisis of 2008: reduced lending standards and a significant increase in indebtedness. The proliferation of financial engineering known as collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) and such products’ insurance by credit default swaps (CDS) made the reduction of lending standards possible. John V. Duca, Subprime Mortgage Crisis, Fed. Rsrv. Hist. (Nov. 22, 2013), https://www.federalreservehistory.org/essays/subprime-mortgage-crisis [https://perma.cc/AVZ7-ECUX] (“In the early and mid-2000s, high-risk mortgages became available from lenders who funded mortgages by repackaging them into pools that were sold to investors.”); Miguel Faria e Castro, Domestic Debt Before and After the Great Recession, FED. Rsrv. Bank of St. Louis (Oct. 16, 2018), https://www.stlouisfed.org/on-the-economy/2018/october/domestic-debt-before-after-great-recession [https://perma.cc/MPC5-EG75] (“Total debt rose rapidly in the years preceding the Great Recession, peaking at 370 percent of GDP shortly after the fall of Lehman [Brothers, up from about 230 percent in 1990].”). For information about the increasing prevalence of cov-lite loans, see Jim Edwards, The Risky ‘Leveraged Loan’ Market Just Sunk to a Whole New Low, Bus. Insider (Feb. 17, 2019, 5:44 AM), https://www.businessinsider.com/leveraged-loan-record-87-percent-covenant-lite-2019-2 [https://perma.cc/NS8K-T359] (providing that since 2010, the volume of loans with lessened protections for investors increased drastically from under 10 percent of loans by volume to well over 80 percent of loans by volume). “Cov-lite” stands for covenant-lite, describing a loan with fewer restrictions on the borrower and fewer protections for the lender. James Chen, Covenant-Lite Loan Definition, Investopedia, https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/covenant-lite-loans.asp [https://perma.cc/9B62-YXHR] (Nov. 30, 2020). “Cov-lite” loans are further discussed in Section II.C, infra.
  24. .Leveraged Loan Primer, supra note 18.
  25. .Int’l Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report: Markets in the Time of COVID-19 30 (2020) (containing an International Monetary Fund discussion of the increase in leveraged loan issuance).
  26. .Sam Fleming, Janet Yellen Sounds Alarm over Plunging Loan Standards, Fin. Times (Oct. 24, 2018), https://www.ft.com/content/04352e76-d792-11e8-a854-33d6f82e62f8 [https://perma.cc/7BSM-L8UY]. Federal Reserve Chairwoman Janet Yellen warned the U.S. needs to deal with a “huge deterioration” in the standards of corporate lending. Id.
  27. .Emerging Threats to Stability: Considering the Systemic Risk of Leveraged Lending Before the H. Subcomm. on Consumer Prot. and Fin. Insts., 116th Cong. (2019) (discussing the threats posed by leveraged loans and collateralized loan obligations); Kristen Haunss, US Senator Warren Presses FSOC on Leveraged Loans as Debt Prices Plunge, Reuters (Mar. 20, 2020, 12:08 PM), https://www.reuters.com/article/warrenloan-fsoc/us-senator-warren-presses-fsoc-on-leveraged-loans-as-debt-prices-plunge-idUSL1N2BD1EL [https://perma.cc/99MB-36RM] (discussing Senator Elizabeth Warren’s request for information from Treasury Secretary Steven Mnuchin).
  28. .Although this definition is not perfect, it is workable given the lack of uniform definition for a leveraged loan. See Zachary L. Pechter, The Case for a Uniform Definition of a Leveraged Loan, 43 Fla. State U. L. Rev. 1409 (2016).
  29. .For more information about credit ratings, see generally Intro to Credit Ratings, Standard & Poor’s Ratings Servs., https://www.spglobal.com/ratings/en/about/intro-to-credit-ratings [https://perma.cc/2DVC-GM7S] (“Credit ratings are forward looking opinions about an issuer’s relative creditworthiness. They provide a common and transparent global language for investors to form a view on and compare the relative likelihood of whether an issuer may repay its debts on time and in full.”).
  30. .London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) was the predominant benchmark interest rate used to determine the cost of short-term borrowing between banks. Julia Kagan, London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR), Investopedia (Mar. 14, 2021), https://www.investopedia.com/terms/l/libor.asp [https://perma.cc/R6NT-2K2F].
  31. .Leveraged Loan Primer, supra note 18.
  32. .See Seung Jung Lee et al., The U.S. Syndicated Term Loan Market: Who Holds What and When?, Fed. Rsrv.: Feds Notes (Nov. 25, 2019), https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/the-us-syndicated-term-loan-market-20191125.htm [https://perma.cc/GGB6-K63T].
  33. .For a discussion of LIBOR, see generally David Hou & David Skeie, Fed. Rsrv. Bank N.Y., Staff Report No. 667, LIBOR: Origins, Economics, Crisis, Scandal, and Reform (2014).
  34. .Laila Kollmorgen, CLOs: How They Work, PineBridge Invs. (Sept. 20, 2019), https://www.pinebridge.com/insights/clos-how-they-work [https://perma.cc/ Q749-2JUK].
  35. .Id.
  36. .Id.
  37. .“The ‘capital stack’ refers to the legal organization of all of the capital placed into a company or secured by an asset through investment or borrowing.” Understanding the Capital Stack and How it Affects Your Investments, JRW Investments, https://www.jrw.com/articles/investment-principles/understanding-the-capital-stack-and-how-it-affects-your-investments [https://perma.cc/AGT7-DSRB] (Feb. 14, 2013).
  38. .See Kollmorgen, supra note 34.
  39. .See id.
  40. .“Diversification is a risk management strategy that mixes a wide variety of investments within a portfolio.” Troy Segal, Diversification, Investopedia, https://www.investopedia.com/terms/d/diversification.asp [https://perma.cc/8FDR-QZYL] (Apr. 21, 2021).
  41. .See infra Part III.
  42. .Id.
  43. .Securities Act of 1933, ch. 38, 48 Stat. 74 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 77a–77aa); Securities Exchange Act of 1934, ch. 404, 48 Stat. 881 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. §§ 78a–78qq).
  44. .U.S. Sec. & Exch. Comm’n, The Laws that Govern the Securities Industry, Investor.gov, https://www.investor.gov/introduction-investing/investing-basics/role-sec/laws-govern-securities-industry [https://perma.cc/P7GA-6Y77].
  45. .These costs are discussed in Section II.A, infra.
  46. .Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111–203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010).
  47. .Courts use the Reves test to determine whether a note is a security. Reves v. Ernst & Young, 494 U.S. 56 (1990).
  48. .Infra Part II.A.1.
  49. .Infra Part II.A.2.; see also 15 U.S.C. § 77q.
  50. .15 U.S.C. § 77e(a) (requiring registration before selling a security in interstate commerce).
  51. .15 U.S.C. § 77d (providing exemptions where registration would not be required under the rule stated in § 77e).
  52. .The cost of registration varies based on the issuer, type, distribution method of that security, and the cost of the associated attorneys’ or other professional fees. See 17 C.F.R. § 230.457 (2021) (setting forth a fee assessment structure for securities registration with the SEC); see, e.g., Alan R. Palmiter, Examples & Explanations for Securities Regulation 123 (7th ed. 2017) (“Professional fees for issuer’s counsel in a typical IPO range from $600,000 to $1,000,000, and for the auditing firm from $500,000 to $900,000.”).
  53. .See Securities Act of 1933, ch. 38, § 11(a), 48 Stat. 82, 82 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 77k(a)) (imposing civil liability on various parties for false registration statements).
  54. .Id.
  55. .15 U.S.C. § 77d(a)(2).
  56. .See Palmiter, supra note 52, at 197.
  57. .Id. at 198.
  58. .Id. at 515.
  59. .Securities Exchange Act of 1934, Pub. L. No. 73-291, § 15, 48 Stat. 895, 895–96 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 78o).
  60. .Investment Advisers Act of 1940, Pub L. No. 76-768, 54. Stat. 847 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C.A §§ 80b-1 to -21).
  61. .Investment Company Act of 1940, Pub. L. No 76-768, 54 Stat. 789 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C.A §§ 80a-1 to -64).
  62. .Id. at § 3..
  63. . Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, § 938, 124 Stat. 1376, 1885 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 78o-7).
  64. .See, e.g., 17 C.F.R. 240.10b-5 (2021) (describing the elements of civil liability); 15 U.S.C. § 77q (describing the elements of criminal liability).
  65. .15 U.S.C. § 77l(a) (providing that a person who buys such noncompliant security is entitled “to recover the consideration paid for such security with interest thereon, less the amount of any income received thereon”).
  66. .15 U.S.C. § 77k(a).
  67. .See Aaron v. SEC, 446 U.S. 680 (1980) (upholding a SEC injunction sought for negligent misrepresentation).
  68. .15 U.S.C. § 77x.
  69. .Lorenzo v. SEC, 139 S.Ct. 1094, 1103 (2019) (quoting SEC v. Cap. Gains Rsch. Bureau, Inc., 375 U.S. 180, 186 (1963)). “Caveat emptor” translates to “let the buyer beware.” Caveat Emptor, Black’s Law Dictionary (11th ed. 2019).
  70. .The SEC may also sue under other laws and regulations, such as Rule 10b-5. 17 C.F.R. 240.10b-5 (2021).
  71. .15 U.S.C. § 77q(a); see also 15 U.S.C. § 77t(b) (“[W]henever it shall appear . . . that any person is engaged or about to engage in any practices which constitute or will constitute a violation of . . . this subchapter, . . . the Commission may . . . enjoin such acts or practices . . . .”); United States v. Naftalin, 441 U.S. 768, 775 (1979) (quoting Cap. Gains Rsch. Bureau, 375 U.S. at 186–87) (stating that the Securities Act was intended “to achieve a high standard of business ethics . . . in every facet of the securities industry”).
  72. .17 C.F.R. § 240.10b-5 (2021). Since its initial use in 1946, Rule 10b-5 has become an integral part of securities regulation. See Kardon v. Nat’l Gypsum Co., 69 F. Supp. 512 (E.D. Pa. 1946). Private actions under Rule 10b-5 were described as “a judicial oak which has grown from little more than a legislative acorn.” Blue Chip Stamps v. Manor Drug Stores, 421 U.S. 723, 737 (1975).
  73. .Rule 10b-5 creates a private cause of action. See Kardon, 73 F. Supp. 798 (E.D. Pa. 1947) (recognizing a private cause of action under Rule 10b-5); Superintendent of Ins. v. Bankers Life & Cas. Co., 404 U.S. 6 (1971) (confirming the existence of a Rule 10b-5 private action). Only actual purchasers or sellers may recover damages. See Birnbaum v. Newport Steel Corp., 193 F.2d 461, 464 (2d Cir. 1952).
  74. .See Matrixx Initiatives, Inc. v. Siracusano, 563 U.S. 27 (2011).
  75. .See Litwin v. Blackstone Grp., L.P., 634 F.3d 706 (2d Cir. 2011).
  76. .See Media Gen., Inc. v. Tomlin, No. 98-cv-1690, 2001 WL 1230880 (D.D.C. Aug. 9, 2001).
  77. .See Amanda Rose, The Shifting Purpose of the Rule 10b-5 Private Right of Action, CLS Blue Sky Blog (June 27, 2017), https://clsbluesky.law.columbia.edu/2017/06/27/the-shifting-purpose-of-the-rule-10b-5-private-right-of-action [https://perma.cc/3S8H-E9SA].
  78. .79A C.J.S. Securities Regulation § 203 (2021).
  79. .In re IBM Corp. Sec. Litig., 163 F.3d 102, 106 (2d Cir. 1998).
  80. .“Efficient market” in this context relies upon, but is different from, the efficient market hypothesis. Analysis under Rule 10b-5 looks to trading activity in a relevant market, not the availability of information on the market. See, e.g., Basic Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U.S. 224, 241–42 (1988).
  81. .See id. (discussing the elements and reliance requirement of Rule 10b-5).
  82. .See Malinowski v. Lichter Grp., LLC, 165 F. Supp. 3d 328, 339 (D. Md. 2016) (providing that presumed reliance is inapplicable to common law fraud cases); Kaufman v. I-Stat Corp., 754 A.2d 1188, 1189 (N.J. 2000) (declining to extend the theory of “fraud on the market” liability to common law fraud claims); Morse v. Abbott Lab., 756 F. Supp. 1108, 1112 (N.D. Ill. 1991) (same).
  83. .26 Richard A. Lord, Williston on Contracts § 69:17 (4th ed. 2021).
  84. .Affiliated Ute Citizens v. United States, 406 U.S. 128, 153 (1972).
  85. .Matrixx Initiatives, Inc. v. Siracusano, 563 U.S. 27, 44 (2011).
  86. .Arnold S. Jacobs, Litigation & Practice Under Rule 10b-5 § 11.01 (1999); see also Rossdeutscher v. Viacom, Inc., 768 A.2d 8, 18 (Del. 2001) (“Rule 10b-5 is almost universally viewed as broader than common law fraud claims.”).
  87. .28 U.S.C. § 1331.
  88. .Kirschner v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765 (S.D.N.Y. May 22, 2020); see discussion infra Section II.B.3.
  89. .This cursory analysis takes the plaintiffs’ allegations as true. Had the case been litigated further, this analysis might have changed as more information became available.
  90. .It is important to note that once an asset is deemed a security and a plaintiff class is certified, settlement becomes the most likely option. See, e.g., Guevoura Fund Ltd. v. Sillerman, No. 1:15-cv-07192, 2019 WL 6889901, at *7 (S.D.N.Y. Dec. 18, 2019) (quoting In re Gilat Satellite Networks, Ltd., No. CV-02-1510, 2007 WL 1191048, at *10 (E.D.N.Y. Apr. 19, 2007) (“Securities class actions are generally complex and expensive to litigate.”).
  91. .Such as a motion to dismiss for failure to state a claim, which applied in the Kirschner decision. Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6).
  92. .Kirschner, 2020 WL 2614765, at *4–5.
  93. .The Southern District of New York decided that the Arrangers were not liable for misstatements made by Millennium, that plaintiffs failed to satisfy Fed. R. Civ. P. 9(b)’s heightened pleading standards for fraud, and disclaimers in the credit agreement gave a “separate and independent basis on which to conclude that Plaintiff’s primary fraud claims . . . are futile.” Kirschner v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., 17 Civ. 6334, 2021 WL 4499084, at *17–*21 (S.D.N.Y. Sept. 30, 2021); Fed. R. Civ. P. 9(b).
  94. .“[U]nless the context otherwise requires . . . [t]he term ‘security’ means any note, stock . . . investment contract . . . or, in general, any interest or instrument commonly known as a ‘security.’” 15 U.S.C. § 77b(a)(1).
  95. .Where an asset is a “stock,” a court uses the test formulated in Landreth Timber Co. v. Landreth, 471 U.S. 681, 686 (1985). If the asset is a “note,” a court uses the Reves “family resemblance” test found in Reves v. Ernst & Young, 494 U.S. 56, 66–67 (1990). If the asset is an “investment contract,” a court will utilize the Howey test from SEC v. W. J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293, 298–99 (1946).
  96. .United Hous. Found., Inc. v. Forman, 421 U.S. 837, 848 (1975); see also SEC v. W. J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293, 298 (1946).
  97. .See generally Elisabeth A. Keller, Introductory Comment: A Historical Introduction to the Securities Act of 1933 and the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 49 Ohio State L.J. 329 (1988); see also Franklin D. Roosevelt, Message to Congress on Federal Supervision of Investment Securities, Am. Presidency Proj., https://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/documents/message-congress-federal-supervision-investment-securities [https://perma.cc/9U3E-MLJ6] (providing that Congress shall “insist that every issue of new securities to be sold in interstate commerce shall be accompanied by full publicity and information, and that no essentially important element attending the issue shall be concealed from the buying public”).
  98. .A “bubble” is a “metaphor that seems to mean any volatile market in which prices have risen dramatically.” Erik F. Gerding, Laws Against Bubbles: An Experimental-Asset-Market Approach to Analyzing Financial Regulation, 2007 Wisc. L. Rev. 977, 979.
  99. .See Eugene F. Fama, Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work, 25 J. Fin. 383 (1970). While this description grossly oversimplifies the Efficient Capital Market Hypothesis, the theory posits that prices more accurately reflect value in actively traded markets where a lot of accurate information is available to investors.
  100. .Benjamas Jirasakuldech et al., Financial Disclosure, Investor Protection and Stock Market Behavior: An International Comparison, 37 R. QUANTITATIVE FIN. & ACCT. 181, 197–200 (2011) (high disclosure companies are less likely to experience high variance in stock market returns).
  101. .See, e.g., Keller, supra note 97 (arguing that severe market opacity preceded the financial crash causing the Great Depression); Martin Neil Baily et al., Brookings Inst., The Origins of the Financial Crisis 7–8 (2008) (CDO and CDS prevalence preceding the Great Financial Crisis led to increased market opacity).
  102. .For more information about the efficient capital markets hypothesis, see Fama, supra note 99.
  103. .Olivia B. Waxman, What Caused the Stock Market Crash of 1929—And What We Still Get Wrong About It, Time (Oct. 24, 2019, 11:30 AM), https://time.com/5707876/1929-wall-street-crash [https://perma.cc/3WX5-JYSW].
  104. .Julie Marks, What Caused the Stock Market Crash of 1929, Hist., https://www.history.com/news/what-caused-the-stock-market-crash-of-1929 [https://perma.cc/E5Q2-6E9P] (Apr. 27, 2021).
  105. .Stephen J. Choi & A.C. Pritchard, Securities Regulation Cases and Analysis 1 (Saul Levmore et al. eds., 5th ed. 2019).
  106. .Erin Coghlan et al., What Really Caused the Great Recession, Inst. for Rsch. on Lab. & Emp. (Sept. 19, 2018), https://irle.berkeley.edu/what-really-caused-the-great-recession [https://perma.cc/6WD7-YXK9].
  107. .“NINJA” refers to loans given to individuals “with no income, no job, and no assets,” while “jumbo loans” refer to large loans for luxury homes. Id.
  108. .Martin Buffet, How Do CDOs and CDSs Influence the Crisis of 2008, 6 Lingnan J. Banking, Fin. & Econ. 17, 18–20 (2016).
  109. .Id. It is important to note, however, that CDOs and CLOs are different in many significant ways. See, e.g., Laila Kollmorgen, CLOs Versus CDOs: What’s the Difference?, PineBridge Invs. (Oct. 31, 2018), https://www.pinebridge.com/en/insights/clos-versus-cdos-whats-the-difference [https://perma.cc/BQ3S-GVZ8] (explaining that CLOs “are backed by corporate credit in the form of leveraged loans” whereas CDOs are “based on mortgages”).
  110. .Buffet, supra note 108.
  111. .Sarah Childress, How Much Did the Financial Crisis Cost?, PBS (May 31, 2012), https://www.pbs.org/wgbh/frontline/article/how-much-did-the-financial-crisis-cost [https://perma.cc/T4YA-ACLG].
  112. .See supra Section II.B.1.
  113. .SEC v. W.J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293 (1946).
  114. .15 U.S.C. § 77b(a)(1).
  115. .Courts have since read the term “solely” to mean “predominantly.” See, e.g., SEC v. Merch. Cap., L.L.C., 483 F.3d. 747, 765–66 (11th Cir. 2007) (explaining that sole control is not necessary; the investor must have no real alternative but the third party as manager).
  116. .W.J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. at 298–300.
  117. .Id. at 298 (“It is therefore reasonable to attach that meaning to the term [‘investment contract’] as used by Congress, especially since such a definition is consistent with the statutory aims.”). See Keller, supra note 97, at 340, 342, 347–48, for a discussion of the statutory aim of Congress to prevent fraud while instilling trust in markets.
  118. .A “note” is “a written promise by one party (the maker) to pay money to another party (the payee) or to bearer.” Note, Black’s Law Dictionary (11th ed. 2019).
  119. .Reves v. Ernst & Young, 494 U.S. 56, 66–67 (1990).
  120. .Id. at 62.
  121. .15 U.S.C. § 77b(a).
  122. .See generally, Keller, supra note 97 (explaining that Congress was concerned with fraud and market manipulation in securities markets).
  123. .Reves, 494 U.S. at 63.
  124. .Id. at 65.
  125. .Id. at 64 (citing Exch. Nat’l Bank of Chi. v. Touche Ross & Co., 544 F.2d 1126, 1138 (2d Cir. 1976)).
  126. .Id. at 65 (citing Touche Ross & Co., 544 F.2d at 1138).
  127. .Id. (citing Chem. Bank v. Arthur Anderson & Co., 726 F.2d 930, 939 (2d Cir. 1984)).
  128. .Id. at 67.
  129. .Id. at 66–67.
  130. .Id. at 66–68.
  131. .Id. at 66 (“[W]e examine the transaction to assess the motivations that would prompt a reasonable seller and buyer to enter into it.”).
  132. .Id. at 68.
  133. .Id. at 66 (quoting SEC v. C.M. Joiner Leasing Corp., 320 U.S. 344, 351 (1943)).
  134. .Compare id. at 68 (notes offered “over an extended period to its 23,000 members, as well as to nonmembers”), with Landreth Timber Co. v. Landreth, 471 U.S. 681, 692 (1985) (holding that a closely held corporation’s stock, not traded on any exchange, is not a “security”), and Tcherepnin v. Knight, 389 U.S. 332, 336 (1967) (holding nonnegotiable but transferable “withdrawable capital shares” in a savings and loan association to be a “security”).
  135. .Banco Espanol de Credito v. Sec. Pac. Nat’l Bank, 973 F.2d 51, 55 (2d Cir. 1992).
  136. .Reves, 494 U.S. at 66. Compare Landreth, 471 U.S. at 687, 693 (relying on public expectations in holding that common stock is a security), with United Hous. Found., Inc. v. Forman, 421 U.S. 837, 851 (1975) (stating that common sense suggests purchasers of residential apartments for personal use in state-subsidized cooperatives “are not likely to believe that in reality they are purchasing investment securities simply because the transaction is evidenced by something called a share of stock”).
  137. .Banco Espanol, 973 F.2d at 55.
  138. .Reves, 494 U.S. at 67.
  139. .Id. at 69 (citing Marine Bank v. Weaver, 455 U.S. 551, 557–58 (1982)).
  140. .Id. (citing Int’l Brotherhood of Teamsters v. Daniel, 439 U.S. 551, 569–70 (1979)) (finding that the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 comprehensively regulated a pension plan to the extent that the Securities Acts did not apply).
  141. .Banco Espanol, 973 F.2d at 55.
  142. .Reves, 494 U.S. at 69.
  143. .Id.
  144. .SEC v. Wallenbrock, 313 F.3d 532, 537 (2002) (citing McNabb v. SEC, 298 F.3d 1126, 1132 (9th Cir. 2002)).
  145. .E.g., Kirschner ex rel. Millennium Lender Claim Tr. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765, at *8, *10 (S.D.N.Y. May 22, 2020) (concluding that notes are not securities despite the mixed motivations of buyers and sellers under the first Reves factor); Resol. Tr. Corp. v. Stone, 998 F.2d 1534, 1540 (10th Cir. 1993) (the public perception factor did not lead to a clear conclusion while the remainder of the Reves factors indicated this was not a security, so the court determined the automobile loan papers at issue were not securities).
  146. .See, e.g., Heine v. Colton, Hartnick, Yamin & Sheresky, 786 F. Supp. 360, 372–73 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 9, 1992) (though no alternative mechanism for reducing risk existed, the first through third Reves factors weighed against classifying the defendant’s fraudulent schemes as “notes”).
  147. .Kirschner, 2020 WL 2614765, at *10. The Southern District of New York’s decision is significant because, as of 2017, about 22 percent of all securities and commodities civil suits are filed in that district—more than double the rate of the next most popular district for such suits. See Securities and Commodities Exchange Litigation Up 37 Percent, TRAC Reps. (June 19, 2017), https://trac.syr.edu/tracreports/civil/473 [https://perma.cc/R3N7-8FFX].
  148. .Kirschner, 2020 WL 2614765, at *10.
  149. .See 17 C.F.R. §240.10b-5 (2021).
  150. .Keller, supra note 97, at 342–52.
  151. .Kirschner, 2020 WL 2614765, at *1.
  152. .Id. at *2.
  153. .Id. at *1.
  154. .Id. at *3 (quoting Compl. ¶¶ 95–96, Kirschner ex rel. Millennium Lender Claim Tr. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765, (S.D.N.Y. Aug. 21, 2017), ECF No. 1-1).
  155. .Id.
  156. .Id. at *4.
  157. .Id. at *4–5.
  158. .Id. at *5.
  159. .Id.
  160. .Id.
  161. .Id. at *10 (quoting Banco Espanol de Credito v. Sec. Pac. Nat’l Bank, 973 F.2d 51, 56 (2d Cir. 1992).
  162. .Id.
  163. .Id. at *8.
  164. .Id.
  165. .Id.
  166. .Id. at *8–9.
  167. .Id. at *8.
  168. .Id. at *8 (quoting Banco Espanol de Credito v. Sec. Pac. Nat’l Bank, 973 F.2d 51, 56 (2d Cir. 1992). Examples of restrictions included assignment only with permission from the lender, no assignment to natural persons, and a $1 million minimum investment amount. Id. at *8.
  169. .See supra text accompanying notes 126–129.
  170. .SEC v. W.J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293, 298–99 (1946).
  171. .Reves v. Ernst & Young, 494 U.S. 56, 65 (1990).
  172. .Kirschner ex rel. Millennium Lender Claim Tr. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765, at *9–10 (S.D.N.Y. May 22, 2020).
  173. .Id. at *9.
  174. .Id.
  175. .Id. at *10 (quoting Memorandum from Richard G. Mason et al., Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, Private Equity, Restructuring and Finance Developments: Trading in Distressed Debt 2 (Jan. 20, 2009), https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/wp-content/uploads/2009/01/trading-in-distressed-debt.pdf [https://perma.cc/D9X2-Q88T].
  176. .Id.
  177. .Reves v. Ernst & Young, 494 U.S. 56, 66–67 (1990).
  178. .Kirschner, 2020 WL 2614765, at *8.
  179. .Id. at *10.
  180. .Kirschner, 2020 WL 2614765, at *10 (analogizing to Banco Espanol de Credito v. Security Pacific Nat’l. Bank, 973 F.2d 51, 55 (S.D.N.Y. June 24, 1992), where the court found that the existence of “policy guidelines addressing the sale of loan participations” issued by the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency created another regulatory scheme and thereby reduced the risk of the instrument).
  181. .Reves, 494 U.S. at 67–69.
  182. .17 C.F.R. §§ 255.3, 255.10 (2021).
  183. .ERISA provides a comprehensive set of laws and regulations to protect investors in retirement funds, backed by the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation, which provides protection to employees’ retirement plans. Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA), U.S. Dep’t of Labor, https://www.dol.gov/general/topic/retirement/erisa [https://perma.cc/EWJ2-S69B].
  184. .These examples are: “[1] the note delivered in consumer financing, [2] the note secured by a mortgage on a home, [3] the short-term note secured by a lien on a small business or some of its assets, [4] the note evidencing a ‘character’ loan to a bank customer, [5] short-term notes secured by an assignment of accounts receivable, [6] a note which simply formalizes an open-account debt incurred in the ordinary course of business (particularly if, as in the case of the customer of a broker, it is collateralized)[, and 7] . . . notes evidencing loans by commercial banks for current operations.” Reves, 494 U.S. at 65.
  185. .Id.
  186. .See id.
  187. .Id.
  188. .The analysis begins by presuming a note is a security, but this presumption is rebuttable upon showing the note “bears a resemblance to one of the instruments identified” in the Reves family. Id. at 65–66 (internal quotations omitted).
  189. .As discussed infra Section II.B.2, though Howey does not apply to notes, the reasoning the Howey Court used should be instructive as to the purpose of the securities laws.
  190. .These elements mirror the requirements to define an investment contract discussed in SEC v. W.J. Howey and its progeny. See SEC v. W. J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293, 298 (1946).
  191. .See infra Section II.B.2.
  192. .Blaise Gadanecz, The Syndicated Loan Market: Structure, Development and Implications, 2004 Bank for Int’l Settlements Q. Rev. 75, 78 (2004), https://www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt0412g.pdf [https://perma.cc/ZVM7-6CSY].
  193. .See, e.g., Keller, supra note 97, at 348–51 (the Exchange Act prohibits numerous schemes which could defraud investors, such as insider trading, manipulative devices, manipulative pricing, and certain broker and dealer activities).
  194. .Fed. Rsrv., Financial Stability Report: May 2020, at 20 (2020). Outstanding leveraged loans are worth $1.193 billion as of Q4 2019. Id.
  195. .Like the Investors in Kirschner, investor syndicates can directly purchase a portion of the loan. See Kirschner ex rel. Millennium Lender Claim Tr. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765, at *3 (S.D.N.Y. 2020).
  196. .Alternatively, investors can purchase shares of a CLO—collateralized loan obligation. See supra Part I.
  197. .Though many people think of “Wall Street” as large funds that have no bearing on everyday Americans, it is important to keep in mind that these funds invest money on behalf of everyday Americans. For example, the funds in Kirschner were mutual funds, pension funds, universities, CLOs, and other institutional investors. Complaint at 7, Kirschner ex rel. Millennium Lender Claim Tr. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765 (S.D.N.Y. Aug. 21, 2017).
  198. .15 U.S.C. § 77b(a)(1).
  199. .15 U.S.C. § 77d(a)(2).
  200. .15 U.S.C. §78j(b).
  201. .17 C.F.R. § 240.10b-5 (2021).
  202. .Brief of Amici Curiae the Loan Syndications and Trading Association and the Bank Policy Institute at 4, Kirschner ex rel. Millennium Lender Claim Tr. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A., 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765 (S.D.N.Y. Apr. 30, 2019) [hereinafter “LSTA Brief”].
  203. .Id. at 8.
  204. .Id. at 3.
  205. .Id.
  206. .Id. at 14.
  207. .LSTA Code of Conduct, Loan Syndications & Trading Ass’n (Dec. 14, 2020), https://www.lsta.org/content/lsta-code-of-conduct [https://perma.cc/YN73-ZWLA] (click “DOWNLOAD,” then scroll down to Section II.B.9.).
  208. .15 U.S.C. § 77d(a)(2).
  209. .One example of private placements is selling some or all of a company’s equity in a merger or acquisition. See, e.g., Joel Crank, Issuances of Securities in M&A Transactions, Colo. Bar Ass’n Bus. Entity Newsl. (Nov. 24, 2021). Another example is selling equity in a startup company to a venture capitalist or angel investor. E.g., AF Bureau, Real-World Private Placement Examples and Their Impact on the Businesses, Alcor Fund (Nov. 2, 2020), https://alcorfund.com/insight/real-world-private-placement-examples-and-their-impact-on-the-businesses [https://perma.cc/XHM4-4EB7]. Another private placement example would be selling hedge fund interests in the fund to accredited investors. Id. Lastly, yet another private placement example would be the sale of a company’s debt. Jason Rothenberg, Metlife Inv. Mgmt. Private Placement Debt Investments (2020), https://investments.metlife.com/content/dam/metlifecom/us/investments/insights/research-topics/private-capital/pdf/MetLife-Investment-Management-Private-Placement-Debt-Investments-Overview.pdf [https://perma.cc/D3C8-JRJE].
  210. .Chen, supra note 23.
  211. .See Protective Covenant, Nasdaq, https://www.nasdaq.com/glossary/p/protective-convenant [https://perma.cc/SYX6-WK34].
  212. .See Loan Covenant, Corp. Fin. Inst., https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/knowledge/finance/loan-covenant [https://perma.cc/QM42-DBF7].
  213. .Chris Cordone, Cov-lite Loans, Financialedge (May 19, 2021), https://www.fe.training/free-resources/private-equity/cov-lite-loans [https://perma.cc/P64X-BBME].
  214. .See Leveraged Loans: Cov-Lite Volume Reaches Yet Another Record High, S&P Glob.: Mkt. Intel. (June 22, 2018, 7:51 PM), https://www.spglobal.com/marketintelligence/en/news-insights/latest-news-headlines/leveraged-loan-news/leveraged-loans-cov-lite-volume-reaches-yet-another-record-high [https://perma.cc/ZKW3-SSTV].
  215. .See Cordone, supra note 213.
  216. .Banco Espanol de Credito v. Sec. Pac. Nat’l Bank, 973 F.2d 51 (2d Cir. 1992).
  217. .Such distress is discussed in Part III, infra.
  218. .This, however, is outside the scope of this Note.
  219. .17 C.F.R. § 255.10(a)(1) (2021).
  220. .Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 § 13, 12 U.S.C. § 1851.
  221. .Depository institutions and other financial organizations including bank holding companies owned over $77 billion worth of AAA-rated CLO tranches issued out of the Cayman Islands as of 2018. Laurie DeMarco et al., Who Owns U.S. CLO Securities? An Update by Tranche, Fed. Rsrv.: FEDS Notes (June 25, 2020), https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/who-owns-us-clo-securities-an-update-by-tranche-20200625.htm [https://perma.cc/YMN8-WBBX]. AAA rated financial instruments are presumed “risk-free.” Chen, supra note 23.
  222. .Andrei Shleifer & Robert Vishny, Fire Sales in Finance and Macroeconomics, 25 J. Econ. Persp. 29, 38–41 (2011).
  223. .See, e.g., Kirschner ex rel. Millennium Lender Claim Tr. v. JPMorgan Chase Bank, N.A, No. 17 Civ. 6334, 2020 WL 2614765 (S.D.N.Y. May 22, 2020).
  224. .Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act § 619, 12 U.S.C. § 1851.
  225. .12 U.S.C. § 1851(a)(1)(B).
  226. .17 C.F.R. § 255.10(a)(1) (2021).
  227. .Id. § 255.10(c)(8)(i)(E)(1).
  228. .Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 § 13, 12 U.S.C. § 1851.
  229. .12 U.S.C. § 1851(g)(2).
  230. .Prohibitions and Restrictions on Proprietary Trading and Certain Interests in, and Relationships with, Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds, 79 Fed. Reg. 5,536, 5,688 (Jan. 31, 2014).
  231. .Id.
  232. .Prohibitions and Restrictions on Proprietary Trading and Certain Interests in, and Relationships with, Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds, 85 Fed. Reg. 46,422, 46,431 (July 31, 2021).
  233. .Id. at 46,432–33; 17 C.F.R. § 255.10(c)(8)(i)(E)(1).
  234. .Prohibitions and Restrictions on Proprietary Trading and Certain Interests in, and Relationships with, Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds, 85 Fed. Reg. at 46,432–33.
  235. .Id. at 46,432–33.
  236. .Note, however, this exclusion does not permit holding non-debt securities in a securitization.
  237. .12 U.S.C. § 1851.
  238. .5 U.S.C. § 706(2)(a).
  239. .LSTA Brief, supra note 202, at 18; US Banks’ CLO Security Holdings Near $100B After 12% Jump in 2019, S&P Global (Mar. 3, 2020), https://www.spglobal.com/marketintelligence/en/news-insights/latest-news-headlines/leveraged-loan-news/us-banks-clo-security-holdings-near-100b-after-12-jump-in-2019 [https://perma.cc/7DZY-ARLM].
  240. .A fire sale is the sale of goods or assets at heavily discounted prices. Will Kenton, Fire Sale, Investopedia, https://www.investopedia.com/terms/f/firesale.asp [https://perma.cc/WF7X-G3MK] (Oct. 23, 2021).
  241. .See generally Andrei Shleifer & Robert W. Vishny, Liquidation Values and Debt Capacity: A Market Equilibrium Approach, 47 J. Fin. 1343 (1992) (observing that the forced liquidation of industry-specific assets may yield transaction prices significantly below fundamental value).
  242. .Triple-A credit ratings are the highest possible credit rating and denote both a high degree of creditworthiness and the lowest possible risk of default. James Chen, AAA, Investopedia (Mar. 31, 2020), https://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/aaa.asp [https://perma.cc/Y5AN-JYZP].
  243. .See Gregg Gelzinis, Bank Capital and the Coronavirus Crisis, Ctr. for Am. Progress (May 12, 2020), https://www.americanprogress.org/issues/economy/reports/2020/05/12/484722/bank-capital-coronavirus-crisis [https://perma.cc/A5HJ-PSAM] (noting that the COVID-19 pandemic placed severe stress on the banking system).
  244. .See Shleifer & Vishny, supra note 222, at 38–41 (discussing the implications of fire sales during the 2008 Great Financial Crisis).
  245. .LSTA Brief, supra note 202, at 17–20.
  246. .Zuhaib Gull, LCD News, CLO Exposure Among US Banks Drops Slightly in Q1, S&P Glob.: Mkt. Intel. (June 25, 2020), https://www.spglobal.com/marketintelligence/en/news-insights/latest-news-headlines/clo-exposure-among-us-banks-drops-slightly-in-q1-59201671 [https://perma.cc/A4F9-FJKD]; US Banks’ CLO Security Holdings Near $100B After 12% Jump in 2019, S&P Glob.: Mkt. Intel. (Mar. 3, 2020), https://www.spglobal.com/marketintelligence/en/news-insights/latest-news-headlines/leveraged-loan-news/us-banks-clo-security-holdings-near-100b-after-12-jump-in-2019 [https://perma.cc/2UKM-ZGLW].
  247. .S.P. Kothari et al., SEC, U.S. Credit Markets: Interconnectedness and the Effects of the COVID-19 Economic Shock 10 (2020), https://www.sec.gov/files/US-Credit-Markets_COVID-19_Report.pdf [https://perma.cc/ZZ3W-5PNE].
  248. .See id.
  249. .See id.
  250. .A “credit crunch” is when “economic conditions . . . make financial organizations less willing to lend money, often causing serious economic problems.” Credit Crunch, Cambridge Dictionary, https://dictionary.cambridge.org/us/dictionary/english/credit-crunch [https://perma.cc/B5NH-66SP].
  251. .17 C.F.R. § 255.10(c)(8) (2021).